Katana VentraIP

Jevons paradox

In economics, the Jevons paradox (/ˈɛvənz/; sometimes Jevons effect) occurs when technological progress increases the efficiency with which a resource is used (reducing the amount necessary for any one use), but the falling cost of use induces increases in demand enough that resource use is increased, rather than reduced.[1][2][3] Governments typically assume that efficiency gains will lower resource consumption, ignoring the possibility of the paradox arising.[4]

In 1865, the English economist William Stanley Jevons observed that technological improvements that increased the efficiency of coal use led to the increased consumption of coal in a wide range of industries. He argued that, contrary to common intuition, technological progress could not be relied upon to reduce fuel consumption.[5][6]


The issue has been re-examined by modern economists studying consumption rebound effects from improved energy efficiency. In addition to reducing the amount needed for a given use, improved efficiency also lowers the relative cost of using a resource, which increases the quantity demanded. This may counteract (to some extent) the reduction in use from improved efficiency. Additionally, improved efficiency increases real incomes and accelerates economic growth, further increasing the demand for resources. The Jevons paradox occurs when the effect from increased demand predominates, and the improved efficiency results in a faster rate of resource utilization.[6]


Considerable debate exists about the size of the rebound in energy efficiency and the relevance of the Jevons paradox to energy conservation. Some dismiss the effect, while others worry that it may be self-defeating to pursue sustainability by increasing energy efficiency.[4] Some environmental economists have proposed that efficiency gains be coupled with conservation policies that keep the cost of use the same (or higher) to avoid the Jevons paradox.[7] Conservation policies that increase cost of use (such as cap and trade or green taxes) can be used to control the rebound effect.[8]

new software will always consume any increase in computing power that new hardware can provide

Andy and Bill's law

Diminishing returns

increasing road capacity can make traffic congestion worse

Downs–Thomson paradox

a phenomenon in which common resources to which access is not regulated tend to become depleted

Tragedy of the commons

faster hardware can trigger the development of less-efficient software

Wirth's law

strong revenue from a dominant sector renders other sectors uncompetitive and starves them

Dutch Disease

Jenkins, Jesse; Nordhaus, Ted; Shellenberger, Michael (February 17, 2011). (Report). Oakland, CA: The Breakthrough Institute. Archived from the original on 25 May 2015. Retrieved 29 May 2015.

Energy Emergence: Rebound and Backfire as Emergent Phenomena

(5 July 2005). "3: The economics of energy efficiency". Select Committee on Science and Technology Second Report (Report). Session 2005–06. London, UK: House of Lords.

Lords Select Committee on Science and Technology

Michaels, Robert J. (July 6, 2012). (PDF) (Report). Washington, D.C.: Institute for Energy Research. Retrieved 5 June 2015.

Energy Efficiency and Climate Policy: The Rebound Dilemma