Katana VentraIP

Profit (economics)

In economics, profit is the difference between revenue that an economic entity has received from its outputs and total costs of its inputs, also known as surplus value.[1] It is equal to total revenue minus total cost, including both explicit and implicit costs.[2]

This article is about profit in economics and political economy. For profit in accounting and business, see Profit (accounting).

It is different from accounting profit, which only relates to the explicit costs that appear on a firm's financial statements. An accountant measures the firm's accounting profit as the firm's total revenue minus only the firm's explicit costs. An economist includes all costs, both explicit and implicit costs, when analyzing a firm. Therefore, economic profit is smaller than accounting profit.[3]


Normal profit is often viewed in conjunction with economic profit. Normal profits in business refer to a situation where a company generates revenue that is equal to the total costs incurred in its operation, thus allowing it to remain operational in a competitive industry. It is the minimum profit level that a company can achieve to justify its continued operation in the market where there is competition. In order to determine if a company has achieved normal profit, they first have to calculate their economic profit. If the company's total revenue is equal to its total costs, then its economic profit is equal to zero and the company is in a state of normal profit. Normal profit occurs when resources are being used in the most efficient way at the highest and best use. Normal profit and economic profit are economic considerations while accounting profit refers to the profit a company reports on its financial statements each period.


Economic profits arise in markets which are non-competitive and have significant barriers to entry, i.e. monopolies and oligopolies. The inefficiencies and lack of competition in these markets foster an environment where firms can set prices or quantities instead of being price-takers, which is what occurs in a perfectly competitive market.[4] In a perfectly competitive market when long-run economic equilibrium is reached, economic profit would become non-existent, because there is no incentive for firms either to enter or to leave the industry.[5]

Other applications of the term[edit]

The social profit from a firm's activities is the accounting profit plus or minus any externalities or consumer surpluses that occur in its activity. An externality including positive externality and negative externality is an effect that production/consumption of a specific good exerts on people who are not involved.[7][10][2] Pollution is an example for negative externality.


Consumer surplus is an economic indicator which measures consumer benefits.[7][10][2] The price that consumers pay for a product is not greater than the price they desire to pay, and in this case there will be consumer surplus.


For the supply side of economics, the general school of thought is that profit is meant to ensure shareholder yield. While it is the case that profits are a means for shareholder returns, it also fulfills other functions. A target surplus may secure long-term solvency in the event of facing potential adversity. Capital surplus may be used to finance investments with significant capital expenditures or charitable contributions. All in all, producer surplus concerns several factors of interest for a for-profit economic entity.[22][23]

Economic surplus

Economic rent

Economic value added

Externality

Inverse demand function

Profit motive

Profitability index

Rate of profit

Superprofit

Surplus value

Tendency of the rate of profit to fall

Value (economics)

Albrecht, William P. (1983). . Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice-Hall. ISBN 0-13-224345-8.

Economics

Carbaugh, Robert J. (January 2006). . Cengage Learning. ISBN 978-0-324-31461-8. Retrieved 3 October 2010.

Contemporary economics: an applications approach

Lipsey, Richard G. (1975). (fourth ed.). Weidenfeld & Nicolson. pp. 214–7. ISBN 0-297-76899-9.

An introduction to positive economics

Chiller, Bradley R. (1991). Essentials of Economics. New York: McGraw-Hill.

Mansfield, Edwin (1979). Micro-Economics Theory and Applications (3rd ed.). New York and London: W.W. Norton and Company.

LeRoy Miller, Roger (1982). Intermediate Microeconomics Theory Issues Applications (3rd ed.). New York: McGraw-Hill.

Tirole, Jean (1988). . Cambridge, Massachusetts: MIT Press. ISBN 9780262200714.

The Theory of Industrial Organization

Black, John (2003). Oxford Dictionary of Economics. New York: Oxford University Press.

Jack Hirshleifer; Amihai Glazer; David Hirshleifer (2005). . Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0-521-81864-3. Retrieved 20 December 2010.

Price theory and applications: decisions, markets, and information

Perloff, Jeffrey (2018). Microeconomics, Global Edition (8 ed.). Harlow, United Kingdom: Pearson Education Limited. pp. 252–272.  9781292215624.

ISBN

Murray Rothbard's Man, Economy, and State, Chapter 8.

Entrepreneurial Profit and Loss