Katana VentraIP

Paul Samuelson

Paul Anthony Samuelson (May 15, 1915 – December 13, 2009) was an American economist who was the first American to win the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences. When awarding the prize in 1970, the Swedish Royal Academies stated that he "has done more than any other contemporary economist to raise the level of scientific analysis in economic theory".[6]

Paul Samuelson

Paul Anthony Samuelson

(1915-05-15)May 15, 1915

December 13, 2009(2009-12-13) (aged 94)

Marion Crawford
(m. 1938; died 1978)
[4]
Risha Clay
(m. 1981)
[5]

Keynes • Schumpeter • Leontief • Haberler • Hansen • Wilson • Wicksell • Lindahl

Samuelson was one of the most influential economists of the latter half of the 20th century.[7][8] In 1996, when he was awarded the National Medal of Science.[6] Samuelson considered mathematics to be the "natural language" for economists and contributed significantly to the mathematical foundations of economics with his book Foundations of Economic Analysis.[9] He was author of the best-selling economics textbook of all time: Economics: An Introductory Analysis, first published in 1948.[10] It was the second American textbook that attempted to explain the principles of Keynesian economics.


Samuelson served as an advisor to President John F. Kennedy and President Lyndon B. Johnson, and was a consultant to the United States Treasury, the Bureau of the Budget and the President's Council of Economic Advisers. Samuelson wrote a weekly column for Newsweek magazine along with Chicago School economist Milton Friedman, where they represented opposing sides: Samuelson, as a self described "Cafeteria Keynesian",[7] claimed taking the Keynesian perspective but only accepting what he felt was good in it.[7] By contrast, Friedman represented the monetarist perspective.[11] Together with Henry Wallich, their 1967 columns earned the magazine a Gerald Loeb Special Award in 1968.[12]

Assistant professor of economics at MIT, 1940; associate professor, 1944.

Member of the Radiation Laboratory 1944–45.

Professor of international economic relations (part-time) at the in 1945.

Fletcher School of Law and Diplomacy

Guggenheim Fellowship from 1948 to 1949

Professor of economics at MIT beginning in 1947 and beginning in 1962.

Institute Professor

Vernon F. Taylor Visiting Distinguished Professor at in spring 1989.

Trinity University (Texas)

where he pioneered the revealed preference approach, which is a method by which one can discern a consumer's utility function, by observing their behavior. Rather than postulate a utility function or a preference ordering, Samuelson imposed conditions directly on the choices made by individuals – their preferences as revealed by their choices.

Consumer theory

in which he popularised the Lindahl–Bowen–Samuelson conditions (criteria for deciding whether an action will improve welfare) and demonstrated in 1950 the insufficiency of a national-income index to reveal which of two social options was uniformly outside the other's (feasible) possibility function (Collected Scientific Papers, v. 2, ch. 77; Fischer, 1987, p. 236).

Welfare economics

where he is known for 1958 consumption loans model and a variety of turnpike theorems and involved in Cambridge capital controversy.

Capital theory

theory, in which he is known for the efficient-market hypothesis.

Finance

theory, in which he is particularly known for his work on determining the optimal allocation of resources in the presence of both public goods and private goods.

Public finance

where he influenced the development of two important international trade models: the Balassa–Samuelson effect, and the Heckscher–Ohlin model (with the Stolper–Samuelson theorem).

International economics

where he popularized the overlapping generations model as a way to analyze economic agents' behavior across multiple periods of time (Collected Scientific Papers, v. 1, ch. 21) and contributed to formation of the neoclassical synthesis.

Macroeconomics

: Samuelson believed unregulated markets have drawbacks, he stated, "free markets do not stabilise themselves. Zero regulating is vastly suboptimal to rational regulating. Libertarianism is its own worst enemy!" Samuelson strongly criticised Friedman and Friedrich Hayek, arguing their opposition to state intervention "tells us something about them rather than something about Genghis Khan or Franklin Roosevelt. It is paranoid to warn against inevitable slippery slopes ... once individual commercial freedoms are in any way infringed upon."[7]

Market economics

As professor of economics at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Samuelson worked in many fields, including:

Examine underlying analogies between central features in theoretical and applied economics and

Study how theorems can be derived with a small number of analogous methods (p. 3),

operationally meaningful

Criticisms[edit]

Textbook influences in higher education[edit]

Samuelson's textbook was a watershed in introducing the serious study of business cycles to the economics curriculum. It was particularly timely because it followed the Great Depression. The study of business cycles along with the introduction of the Keynesian approach of aggregate demand set the stage for the macroeconomic revolution in America, which then diffused throughout the world through translations into every major language. Generations of students, who then became teachers, learned their first and most influential lessons from Samuelson's Economics. It attracted many imitators, who became successful in different niches of the college market.


The text was not without criticism. While it praised the "mixed economy" of market and government, some found that too radical and attacked it as socialist. As a precursor to criticisms of Samuelson's Economics textbook, Lorie Tarshis's textbook was attacked by trustees of, and donors to, American colleges and universities as preaching a "socialist heresy".[35] Piling on, William F. Buckley, Jr., in his 1951 book, God and Man at Yale, devoted an entire chapter, attacking both Samuelson's and Tarshis' textbooks. For Samuelson's book, Buckley drew from the Educational Examiner and credited it as an "excellent review of Samuelson's text." ("Note to Chapter Two." p. 234)[36][a] For Tarshis' book, Buckley drew from Merwin K. Hart's organization to wit: "I am also grateful to the National Economic Council for its telling analysis of the Tarshis." ("Note to Chapter Two." p. 234)[36] Buckley essentially characterized both as – in the words of Paul Davidson – "communist inspired".[36][34] Buckley, for the rest of his life, defended the criticisms set forth in his book.

Economic growth of USSR[edit]

One criticism – of a concept that Samuelson added to his Economics textbook – was the comparison of USA growth rates with those of the USSR, which, according to the criticism, was inconsistent with historical GNP differences.[37] The textbook's 1967 edition (7th ed.) extrapolates (projects) the possibility of USSR/US real GNP parity between 1977 and 1995. Each subsequent edition extrapolates a date range further in the future until those graphs were dropped from the 1985 edition (12th ed.).[38]

Phillips Curve[edit]

Samuelson, together with Robert Solow, helped develop and popularize the mathematics of the Phillips Curve. The curve suggested that unemployment and inflation were inversely related; with the advent of stagflation in the 1970s some economists including Milton Friedman and Friedrich Hayek attacked the economics based on the Phillips Curve as questionable or mistaken.

Member of the ,[39] the American Philosophical Society,[40] the United States National Academy of Sciences,[41] fellow of Royal Society of London

American Academy of Arts and Sciences

Fellow of the and the British Academy;

American Philosophical Society

President (1965–68) of the

International Economic Association

Member and past president (1961) of the

American Economic Association

Member of the editorial board and past president (1951) of the

Econometric Society

Fellow, council member and past vice-president of the .

Royal Economic Society

Member of .

Phi Beta Kappa

Samuelson, Paul A. (1947), Enlarged ed. 1983. , Harvard University Press.

Foundations of Economic Analysis

Samuelson, Paul A. (1948), , ISBN 0-07-074741-5; with William D. Nordhaus (since 1985), 2009, 19th ed., McGraw–Hill. ISBN 978-0-07-126383-2

Economics: An Introductory Analysis

Samuelson, Paul A. (1952), "Economic Theory and Mathematics – An Appraisal", American Economic Review, 42(2), pp. .

56–66

Samuelson, Paul A (1954). "The Pure Theory of Public Expenditure". Review of Economics and Statistics. 36 (4): 387–89. :10.2307/1925895. JSTOR 1925895. S2CID 153571905.

doi

Samuelson, Paul A. (1958), Linear Programming and Economic Analysis with and Robert M. Solow, McGraw–Hill. Chapter-preview links.

Robert Dorfman

Samuelson, Paul A. (1960). "Efficient paths of capital accumulation in terms of the calculus of variations". In ; Karlin, Samuel; Suppes, Patrick (eds.). Mathematical models in the social sciences, 1959: Proceedings of the first Stanford symposium. Stanford mathematical studies in the social sciences, IV. Stanford, California: Stanford University Press. pp. 77–88. ISBN 9780804700214.

Arrow, Kenneth J.

Samuelson, Paul A. (1982). "Quesnay's 'Tableau Economique' as a theorist would formulate it today". In ; Bradley, Ian C.; Howard, Michael C. (eds.). Classical and Marxian political economy: essays in honour of Ronald L. Meek. London: Macmillan. pp. 45–78. ISBN 9780333321997. {{cite book}}: |editor-first1= has generic name (help)

Meek, Ronald (author)

The Collected Scientific Papers of Paul A. Samuelson, MIT Press. Preview links for vol. 1–3 below. Contents links for vol. 4–7.  1079936608 (all editions).

OCLC

(2017). Founder of Modern Economics: Paul A. Samuelson: Volume 1: Becoming Samuelson, 1915–1948. Oxford University Press. ISBN 978-0-19-066411-4. Description & arrow-scrollable preview.

Backhouse, Roger E.

Fischer, Stanley (1987). Samuelson, Paul Anthony. Vol. 4. London: Macmillan. pp. 234–41.  978-0-935859-10-2. {{cite book}}: |work= ignored (help).

ISBN

Silk, Leonard (1976). . New York: Basic Books. ISBN 978-0-465-01810-9..

The Economists

(1980). The Worldly Economists. New York: Free Press. ISBN 978-0-02-929780-3..

Sobel, Robert

Fusfeld, Daniel R. (2002). . The Age of the Economist (9th ed.). Boston: Addison-Wesley. pp. 198–201. ISBN 978-0-321-08812-3..

"The Neoclassical Synthesis"

. Forum (in Swedish). No. 1973–17. October 31, 1973. p. 07-09. ISSN 0533-070X.{{cite news}}: CS1 maint: date and year (link)

"I inkomstpolitiken tvår vi våra händer"

at the Mathematics Genealogy Project

Paul Samuelson

on Nobelprize.org

Paul A. Samuelson

by Professor Assar Lindbeck, Stockholm School of Economics, Award Ceremony, The Bank of Sweden Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel, 1970

Presentation Speech

2004

A History of Economic Thought biography

. The Concise Encyclopedia of Economics. Library of Economics and Liberty (2nd ed.). Liberty Fund. 2009.

"Paul Anthony Samuelson (1915–2009)"

Yale Honorands biography, May 2005

Paul Samuelson

MIT News, December 13, 2009

"Nobel-winning economist Paul A. Samuelson dies at age 94"

at Internet Archive

Works by or about Paul Samuelson

on C-SPAN

Appearances

publications indexed by Google Scholar

Paul Samuelson