Katana VentraIP

Institutional economics

Institutional economics focuses on understanding the role of the evolutionary process and the role of institutions in shaping economic behavior. Its original focus lay in Thorstein Veblen's instinct-oriented dichotomy between technology on the one side and the "ceremonial" sphere of society on the other. Its name and core elements trace back to a 1919 American Economic Review article by Walton H. Hamilton.[1][2] Institutional economics emphasizes a broader study of institutions and views markets as a result of the complex interaction of these various institutions (e.g. individuals, firms, states, social norms). The earlier tradition continues today as a leading heterodox approach to economics.[3]

"Traditional" institutionalism rejects the reduction of institutions to simply tastes, technology, and nature (see naturalistic fallacy).[4] Tastes, along with expectations of the future, habits, and motivations, not only determine the nature of institutions but are limited and shaped by them. If people live and work in institutions on a regular basis, it shapes their world views. Fundamentally, this traditional institutionalism (and its modern counterpart institutionalist political economy) emphasizes the legal foundations of an economy (see John R. Commons) and the evolutionary, habituated, and volitional processes by which institutions are erected and then changed (see John Dewey, Thorstein Veblen, and Daniel Bromley). Institutional economics focuses on learning, bounded rationality, and evolution (rather than assuming stable preferences, rationality and equilibrium). It was a central part of American economics in the first part of the 20th century, including such famous but diverse economists as Thorstein Veblen, Wesley Mitchell, and John R. Commons.[5] Some institutionalists see Karl Marx as belonging to the institutionalist tradition, because he described capitalism as a historically bounded social system; other institutionalist economists disagree with Marx's definition of capitalism, instead seeing defining features such as markets, money and the private ownership of production as indeed evolving over time, but as a result of the purposive actions of individuals.


A significant variant is the new institutional economics from the later 20th century, which integrates later developments of neoclassical economics into the analysis. Law and economics has been a major theme since the publication of the Legal Foundations of Capitalism by John R. Commons in 1924. Since then, there has been heated debate on the role of law (a formal institution) on economic growth.[6] Behavioral economics is another hallmark of institutional economics based on what is known about psychology and cognitive science, rather than simple assumptions of economic behavior.


Some of the authors associated with this school include Robert H. Frank, Warren Samuels, Marc Tool, Geoffrey Hodgson, Daniel Bromley, Jonathan Nitzan, Shimshon Bichler, Elinor Ostrom, Anne Mayhew, John Kenneth Galbraith and Gunnar Myrdal, but even the sociologist C. Wright Mills was highly influenced by the institutionalist approach in his major studies.

Institutionalism today[edit]

The earlier approach was a central element in American economics in the interwar years after 1919, but was marginalized relative to mainstream economics in the postwar period with the ascendence of neoclassical and Keynesian approaches. It continued, however, as a leading heterodox approach in critiquing neoclassical economics and as an alternative research program in economics, most notably through the work of Ha-Joon Chang and Geoffrey Hodgson


The leading Swedish economist Lars Pålsson Syll is a believer in institutional economics.[15] He is an outspoken opponent to all kinds of social constructivism and postmodern relativism.[16]

Criticism[edit]

Critics of institutionalism have maintained that the concept of "institution" is so central for all social science that it is senseless to use it as a buzzword for a particular theoretical school. And as a consequence, the elusive meaning of the concept of "institution" has resulted in a bewildering and never-ending dispute about which scholars are "institutionalists" or not—and a similar confusion about what is supposed to be the core of the theory. In other words, institutional economics has become so popular because it means all things to all people, which in the end of the day is the meaning of nothing.[17]


Indeed, it can be argued that the term "institutionalists" was misplaced from the very beginning, since Veblen, Hamilton and Ayres were preoccupied with the evolutionary (and "objectifying") forces of technology and institutions had a secondary place within their theories. Institutions were almost a kind of "anti-stuff"; their key concern was on technology and not on institutions. Rather than being "institutional," Veblen, Hamilton and Ayres’ position is anti-institutional.[17]

and article-abstract links to 2008.

Journal of Economic Issues

with links to selected articles and to article abstracts.

Journal of Institutional Economics

Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics

Evolutionary and Institutional Economics Review

(2011). The Foundations of Institutional Economics, Routledge.

Kapp, K. William

Bromley, Daniel (2006). Sufficient Reason: Volitional Pragmatism and the Meaning of Economic Institutions, Princeton University Press.

(2002). Globalization, Economic Development and the Role of the State, Zed Books.

Chang, Ha-Joon

(1970). "The Structure of a Contract and the Theory of a Non-Exclusive Resource," Journal of Law and Economics, 13(1), pp. 49–70.

Cheung, Steven N. S.

Commons, John R. (1931). "Institutional Economics," American Economic Review Vol. 21 : p .

pp. 648–57

_____ (1931). "Institutional Economics," American Economic Review, Vol. 21, No. 4 (Dec.), Vol. 26, No. 1, (1936): .

pp. 237–49

_____ (1934 [1986]). Institutional Economics: Its Place in Political Economy, Macmillan. and preview.

Description

Davis, John B. (2007). "The Nature of Heterodox Economics," Post-autistic Economics Review, issue no. 40.

[1]

_____, “Why Is Economics Not Yet a Pluralistic Science?”, Post-autistic Economics Review, issue no. 43, 15 September, pp. 43–51.

(2001). "Can Institutions Resolve Ethnic Conflict?" Economic Development and Cultural Change, Vol. 49, No. 4), pp. 687–706 Archived 2017-07-04 at the Wayback Machine.

Easterly, William

Fiorito, Luca and Massimiliano Vatiero, (2011). "Beyond Legal Relations: Wesley Newcomb Hohfeld's Influence on American Institutionalism". Journal of Economics Issues, 45 (1): 199–222.

Galbraith, John Kenneth, (1973). "Power & the Useful Economist," American Economic Review 63:1–11.

Hodgson, Geoffrey M. (1998). "The Approach of Institutional Economics," Journal of Economic Literature, 36(1), pp. (close Bookmarks).

166–92

_____, ed. (2003). Recent Developments in Institutional Economics, Elgar. and contents.

Description

_____ (2004). The Evolution of Institutional Economics: Agency, Structure and Darwinism in American Institutionalism, London and New York: Routledge.

and Thorbjørn Knudsen, "Darwin's Conjecture" The Montreal Review (August, 2011).

Geoffrey M. Hodgson

Hodgson, Samuels, & Tool (1994). The Elgar Companion to Institutional & Evolutionary Economics, Edward Elgar.

Keaney, Michael, (2002). "Critical Institutionalism: From American Exceptionalism to International Relevance", in Understanding Capitalism: Critical Analysis From Karl Marx to Amartya Sen, ed. Doug Dowd, Pluto Press.

Nicita, A., and M. Vatiero (2007). “The Contract and the Market: Towards a Broader Notion of Transaction?”. Studi e Note di Economia, 1:7–22.

North, Douglass C. (1990). Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance, Cambridge University Press.

(2005). "Doing Institutional Analysis: Digging Deeper than Markets and Hierarchies," Handbook of New Institutional Economics, C. Ménard and M. Shirley, eds. Handbook of New Institutional Economics, pp. 819–848. Springer.

Elinor Ostrom

Rutherford, Malcolm (2001). "Institutional Economics: Then and Now," Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 15, No. 3 (Summer), .

pp. 173–94

_____ (2011). The Institutionalist Movement in American Economics, 1918-1947: Science and Social Control, Cambridge University Press.

Li, Rita Yi Man (2011). "Everyday Life Application of Neo-institutional Economics: A Global Perspective", Germany, Lambert.

Schmid, A. Allan (2004). Conflict & Cooperation: Institutional & Behavioral Economics, Blackwell.

Samuels, Warren J. (2007), The Legal-Economic Nexus, Routledge.

From (2008):

The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics

Association for Evolutionary Economics

World Interdisciplinary Network for Institutional Research

Douglass North Nobel lecture

Institutional & Behavioral Economics

Archived 2009-03-19 at the Wayback Machine

American Institutional School

Thorstein Veblen, Bibliography

T. Veblen: The Leisureclass

T. Veblen: Why is Economics Not an Evolutionary Science?

T. Veblen: The Beginning of Ownership av Thorstein Veblen

T. Veblen: Theory of Business Enterprise

Geoffrey Hodgson's website